Indicadores Financieros y Económicos
Financing Decisions: An Approach for the 21st Century
Financing Decisions: An Approach for the 21st Century
Mercados y Negocios, núm. 53, pp. 155-172, 2024
Universidad de Guadalajara
Businesses are the essential engine of development in a nation's economy. By improving their profitability and competitiveness, they reduce the risk of failure and boost GDP growth and job creation. This, in turn, encourages investment and promotes a more equitable income distribution, contributing to society's general well-being (Romero, 2013).
Organizations require financial resources to support their investments in tangible and intangible assets, such as facilities, machinery, research, and critical personnel for operation and management. These resources come from capital contributions by shareholders, reinvestment of profits, or the contracting of external debt. Research on capital or debt decisions must consider multiple factors, such as the risk of failure, growth opportunities, and equitable financial performance with the capital provided or the financing used (Cassar, 2004).
Financing strategies, a key factor of competitiveness, have strongly influenced corporate financial performance and national economic development. It is crucial to thoroughly investigate the variables and their impact when contracting debt to incorporate the appropriate amounts into companies' overall strategy, thus improving their competitiveness.
In the business world, whether there is an optimal capital structure and how it should be constructed is one of the most debated topics in the financial literature. Since Modigliani and Miller's influential 1958 paper introduced the idea of the irrelevance of capital structure to the firm's value, three main theories have emerged. These theories, which dominate the theoretical and empirical discussion, seek to test the assumptions and variables underpinning an optimal corporate and global capital structure.
Multiple theories and research have analyzed the corporate financial structure, yielding diverse results and without achieving a consensus on a single explanation of financing decisions. This is why it is necessary to deepen the research to understand which variables influence the choice between debt and equity and which theories best explain this decision (Hernández & Ríos, 2012).
Organizations must establish clear policies and procedures to ensure the necessary resources to finance their tangible and intangible investments, with financial debt being one of the primary sources of external financing (Denis & Mihov, 2003). However, few empirical studies examine the impact of the internal variables of the business and external variables of the national environment on the contracting and incorporation of debt and their effect on the capital structure (WACC), which is crucial for decision-making oriented toward achieving an optimal capital structure.
Understanding the impact of the determinants of incorporating financial debt into the capital structure is essential to establish guidelines that guide the appropriate financing sources. These guidelines should align with the company's overall strategy and lead to an optimal capital structure. This issue is crucial, as financial policy and capital structure are critical aspects of economic policy. In addition, it has been observed that business failure, especially in small firms, is strongly linked to financial leverage (Ang, 1991; Berger & Udell, 1998).
The optimal capital structure: This is achieved when the increase in insolvency and agency costs perfectly balances the marginal fiscal savings from debt. Maximizing the company's value requires minimizing the weighted average cost of capital as long as the cash flow is not affected by increased leverage. A favorable leverage effect is essential to improve the profitability and value of the company; otherwise, negative leverage would reduce both indicators.
Static Trade-Off Theory
Kraus and Litzenberg's theory of static equilibrium holds that the optimal capital structure is reached when the balance between the costs of financial distress and the tax benefits of debt is ideal. This structure sits at the point where any additional debt would cause the insolvency costs to outweigh the tax benefits. When deciding on the level of financial leverage, companies must evaluate factors such as business risk, financial hardship costs, shareholder and management risk aversion, and internal variables such as total assets, tangible assets, equity, sales, and operating profits. In addition, external variables such as the tax rate, inflation, exchange parity, and interest rates must be considered.
The optimal capital structure maximizes the company's market value by effectively managing the factors influencing financial leverage. The goal is to maintain this structure as long as conditions remain stable. Since the seminal work of Modigliani and Miller, capital structure theory has been central to financial research, focused on finding the optimal structure (Shyam-Sunder & Myers, 1998).
When combined with taxes, financial hardship costs, agency costs, and asymmetric information, Modigliani and Miller's theory shows that the increase in financial leverage reaches a point where its adverse effects balance the benefits. This point, the optimal capital structure, is where the company's value is maximized.
Bradley, Harrel, and Kim (1984) showed that the optimal capital structure depends on the balance between the tax benefits of debt and the costs associated with leverage. They concluded that this structure reflects the influence of various economic costs derived from corporate indebtedness.
Financial leverage decisions must balance the tax benefits of interest with the costs associated with economic hardship, agency costs, and information asymmetry. The objective is to optimize leverage to maximize the company's value and minimize the weighted average cost of capital (Vargas, 2011).
Theoretical and empirical discussions on capital structure have sought to validate the assumptions and variables that explain the combination of resources in business financing policy. These discussions are based on the three main theories mentioned below:
1. Modigliani and Miller: Position I and Position II
2. Trade-Off Theory
3. Peckin Order Theory
1. Analysis of the Theoretical Postulates of Modigliani and Miller (M&M)
In recent decades, several theoretical models have sought to validate and generalize the theses of irrelevance and maximum indebtedness proposed by M&M in 1958 and 1963, respectively. The convergence of these investigations has given rise to a renewed theory of capital structure that postulates the existence of an optimal structure.
1.1 Proposition I, Modigliani and Miller, 1958 (Irrelevance Thesis, without taxes)
Modigliani and Miller argued that, under certain assumptions, a company's value and weighted average cost of capital are independent of its financial structure, concluding that debt does not add value in the absence of taxes. Its assumptions include a perfect capital market, no transaction costs and bankruptcy, and symmetry in information. In this scenario, debt and equity are irrelevant, and internal and external funds are interchangeable. However, this irrelevance needs to reflect the capital structures observed in practice.
1.2 Proposition II, Modigliani and Miller, 1963 (Maximum Indebtedness Thesis, with taxes)
In 1963, M&Ms revised their initial theory to include taxes, proposing that the tax deductibility of interest causes the value of a company to increase with the use of debt, peaking when it is financed almost exclusively by it. However, subsequent studies showed that this benefit is limited, as companies have other avenues of tax savings. Over time, M&M's assumptions were adjusted, giving rise to alternative theories incorporating factors such as agency costs and information asymmetry. The existence of taxes and bankruptcy costs justifies the relevance of the debt. Theories such as those of De Angelo and Masulis (1980), Myers (1984), and Ross (2014) highlight the importance of information asymmetry in the financial structure. In addition, Jensen and Meckling's (1976) agency cost theory addresses conflicts between managers, shareholders, and creditors, which can generate agency costs that decrease the firm's value.
2. Trade-Off Theory
Trade-off theory is positioned as an intermediate approach between M&M's theses, recognizing the market's imperfections and accepting the existence of an optimal capital structure. Bradley, Jarrel, and Kim (1984) argued that corporations set a target level of debt to take advantage of tax benefits while avoiding the limitations of issuing new capital. According to this theory, an optimal combination of debt and equity maximizes the company's value by balancing the benefits and costs of debt. However, it must explain why some financially sound firms do not use their borrowing capacity or why borrowing remains high in low-tax countries.
3. Pecking Order Theory (Hierarchy of Preferences)
The Hierarchy of Preferences (TPO) Theory, formally proposed by Myers (1984) and Myers and Majluf (1984) and based on the work of Donaldson (1961), as well as Agency Cost Theory and Free Cash Flow Theory, suggests that firms prioritize the use of internal funds generated by profits. Followed by debt and, finally, the issuance of external capital. This hierarchy is due to asymmetric information and lower domestic financing and debt costs than equity issuance. This theory prioritizes self-financing, suggesting that the most profitable companies tend to self-finance by generating higher profits and reducing their dependence on external financing through debt (Lemmon & Zender, 2010). Thus, this theory establishes a negative relationship between the debt level and organizations' operating profitability (Tudose, 2012).
It has been 66 years since the seminal work of Modigliani and Miller (1958) laid the foundations of modern corporate finance. Since then, capital structure has been a central topic in finance and economics. However, research has not offered conclusive answers about the capital structure theory. Understanding the theoretical postulates and the impact of debt on the capital structure is crucial to informing debt policies, strengthening financial strategies, and making informed decisions that ensure competitive advantages and solid economic performance.
Market timing and stakeholder theories have recently emerged, bringing new perspectives to studying capital structure. Despite the advances, a model that considers all the determinants of the capital structure has yet to be developed. Recent evidence indicates that macroeconomic and institutional factors in each country are crucial in addition to company-specific factors. Researchers such as Booth et al. (2001), Antoniou et al. (2008), and Gaytán and Bonales (2009) highlight the significant influence of the economic environment and institutional mechanisms on capital structure. Arias et al. (2009) underline the importance of investigating the determinants of WACC in companies from different sectors and countries, especially in Mexico, to design appropriate financial instruments and improve financing decisions.
Economic and financial indicators are useful tools that benefit organizations by facilitating timely and appropriate decision-making about their corporate and financial strategies.
Next, the evolution of some economic and financial indicators of the Mexican environment is described and shown to facilitate decision-making related to personal and business strategies in an integral manner.
1. NATIONAL CONSUMER PRICE INDEX (INPC)
Born in 1995 and reflecting changes in consumer prices, it measures the general price increase in the country. The Bank of Mexico and INEGI calculate it fortnightly (2021). INPC is published in the Official Gazette of the Federation on the 10th and 25th of each month. The reference period is the second half of July 2018.
Period | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 | 2021 | 2022 | 2023 | 2024 |
January | 0.79 | 0.90 | -0.09 | 0.38 | 1.70 | 0.53 | 0.09 | 0.48 | 0.86 | 0.59 | 0.76 | 0.89 |
February | 1.46 | 1.15 | 0.09 | 0.82 | 2.29 | 0.91 | 0.06 | 0.90 | 1.50 | 1.43 | 1.24 | 0.99 |
March | 1.99 | 1.43 | 0.51 | 0.97 | 2.92 | 1.24 | 0.44 | 0.85 | 2.34 | 2.43 | 1.51 | 1.28 |
April | 1.81 | 1.24 | 0.25 | 0.65 | 3.04 | 0.90 | 0.50 | -0.17 | 2.67 | 2.98 | 1.49 | 1.48 |
May | 0.95 | 0.91 | -0.26 | 0.20 | 2.92 | 0.73 | 0.21 | 0.22 | 2.88 | 3.17 | 1.27 | 1.29 |
June | 1.12 | 1.09 | -0.09 | 0.31 | 3.18 | 1.12 | 0.27 | 0.76 | 3.43 | 4.04 | 1.37 | 1.68 |
July | 1.14 | 1.42 | 0.06 | 0.57 | 3.57 | 1.66 | 0.65 | 1.43 | 4.04 | 4.81 | 1.86 | 2.74 |
August | 1.31 | 1.73 | 0.27 | 0.86 | 4.08 | 2.26 | 0.63 | 1.82 | 4.24 | 5.54 | 2.42 | |
September | 1.61 | 2.18 | 0.27 | 1.47 | 4.41 | 2.69 | 0.89 | 2.06 | 4.88 | 6.19 | 2.88 | |
October | 2.77 | 2.74 | 1.16 | 2.09 | 5.06 | 3.22 | 1.44 | 2.68 | 5.76 | 6.79 | 3.27 | |
November | 4.57 | 3.57 | 1.71 | 2.89 | 6.15 | 4.10 | 2.26 | 2.76 | 6.97 | 7.41 | 3.93 | |
December | 5.21 | 4.08 | 2.13 | 3.36 | 6.77 | 4.83 | 2.83 | 3.15 | 7.35 | 7.82 | 4.66 |
2. THE PRICE AND QUOTATION INDEX OF THE MEXICAN STOCK EXCHANGE (IPC)
Represents the change in the values traded on the Mexican Stock Exchange concerning the previous day to determine the percentage of rising or falling of the most representative shares of the companies listed therein.
Period | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 | 2021 | 2022 | 2023 | 2024 |
January | 45,278 | 40,879 | 40,951 | 43,631 | 47,001 | 50,456 | 43,988 | 44,862 | 42,986 | 51,331 | 54,564 | 57,373 |
February | 44,121 | 38,783 | 44,190 | 43,715 | 46,857 | 47,438 | 42,824 | 41,324 | 44,593 | 53,401 | 52,758 | 55,414 |
March | 44,077 | 40,462 | 43,725 | 45,881 | 48,542 | 46,125 | 43,281 | 34,554 | 47,246 | 56,537 | 53,904 | 57,369 |
April | 42,263 | 40,712 | 44,582 | 45,785 | 49,261 | 48,354 | 44,597 | 36,470 | 48,010 | 51,418 | 55,121 | 56,728 |
May | 41,588 | 41,363 | 44,704 | 45,459 | 48,788 | 44,663 | 42,749 | 36,122 | 50,886 | 51,753 | 52,736 | 55,179 |
June | 40,623 | 42,737 | 45,054 | 45,966 | 49,857 | 47,663 | 43,161 | 37,716 | 50,290 | 47,524 | 53,526 | 52,440 |
July | 40,838 | 43,818 | 44,753 | 46,661 | 51,012 | 49,698 | 40,863 | 37,020 | 50,868 | 48,144 | 54,819 | 53,094 |
August | 39,492 | 45,628 | 43,722 | 47,541 | 51,210 | 49,548 | 42,623 | 36,841 | 53,305 | 44,919 | 53,021 | 51,986 |
September | 40,185 | 44,986 | 42,633 | 47,246 | 50,346 | 49,504 | 43,011 | 37,459 | 51,386 | 44,627 | 50,875 | |
October | 41,039 | 45,028 | 44,543 | 48,009 | 48,626 | 43,943 | 43,337 | 36,988 | 51,310 | 49,922 | 49,062 | |
November | 42,499 | 44,190 | 43,419 | 45,286 | 47,092 | 41,733 | 42,820 | 41,779 | 49,699 | 51,685 | 54,060 | |
December | 42,727 | 43,146 | 42,998 | 45,643 | 49,354 | 41,640 | 43,541 | 44,067 | 53,272 | 48,464 | 57,386 |
3. EXCHANGE RATE
It is the value of the Mexican peso relative to the dollar calculated using the daily average of the five most important banks in the country. It reflects the spot price (cash) negotiated between banks. It is highly related to Inflation, the interest rate, and the Mexican Stock Exchange.
Period | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 | 2021 | 2022 | 2023 | 2024 |
January | 12.71 | 13.37 | 14.69 | 18.45 | 21.02 | 18.62 | 19.04 | 18.91 | 20.22 | 20.74 | 18.79 | 17.16 |
February | 12.87 | 13.30 | 14.92 | 18.17 | 19.83 | 18.65 | 19.26 | 19.78 | 20.94 | 20.65 | 18.40 | 17.06 |
March | 12.36 | 13.08 | 15.15 | 17.40 | 18.81 | 18.33 | 19.38 | 23.48 | 20.44 | 19.99 | 18.11 | 16.53 |
April | 12.16 | 13.14 | 15.22 | 19.40 | 19.11 | 18.86 | 19.01 | 23.93 | 20.18 | 20.57 | 18.07 | 17.09 |
May | 12.63 | 12.87 | 15.36 | 18.45 | 18.51 | 19.75 | 19.64 | 22.18 | 19.92 | 19.69 | 17.56 | 17.01 |
June | 13.19 | 13.03 | 15.57 | 18.91 | 17.90 | 20.06 | 19.21 | 23.09 | 19.91 | 20.13 | 17.07 | 18.24 |
July | 12.73 | 13.06 | 16.21 | 18.86 | 17.69 | 18.55 | 19.99 | 22.20 | 19.85 | 20.34 | 16.73 | 18.59 |
August | 13.25 | 13.08 | 16.89 | 18.58 | 17.88 | 19.07 | 20.07 | 21.89 | 20.06 | 20.09 | 16.84 | 19.60 |
September | 13.01 | 13.45 | 17.01 | 19.50 | 18.13 | 18.90 | 19.68 | 22.14 | 20.56 | 20.09 | 17.62 | |
October | 12.89 | 13.42 | 16.45 | 18.84 | 19.15 | 19.80 | 19.16 | 21.25 | 20.53 | 19.82 | 18.08 | |
November | 13.09 | 13.72 | 16.55 | 20.55 | 18.58 | 20.41 | 19.61 | 20.14 | 21.45 | 19.40 | 17.14 | |
December | 13.08 | 14.72 | 17.21 | 20.73 | 19.79 | 19.68 | 18.87 | 19.91 | 20.47 | 19.47 | 16.89 |
4. EQUILIBRIUM INTERBANK INTEREST RATE (TIIE)
On March 23, 1995, the Bank of Mexico, to establish an interbank interest rate that better reflects market conditions, released the Interbank Equilibrium Interest Rate through the Official Gazette of the Federation.
Period | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 | 2021 | 2022 | 2023 | 2024 |
January | 4.84 | 3.78 | 3.29 | 3.56 | 6.15 | 7.66 | 8.59 | 7.50 | 4.47 | 5.72 | 10.82 | 11.50 |
February | 4.80 | 3.79 | 3.29 | 4.05 | 6.61 | 7.83 | 8.54 | 7.29 | 4.36 | 6.02 | 11.27 | 11.50 |
March | 4.35 | 3.81 | 3.30 | 4.07 | 6.68 | 7.85 | 8.51 | 6.74 | 4.28 | 6.33 | 11.43 | 11.44 |
April | 4.33 | 3.80 | 3.30 | 4.07 | 6.89 | 7.85 | 8.50 | 6.25 | 4.28 | 6.73 | 11.54 | 11.25 |
May | 4.30 | 3.79 | 3.30 | 4.10 | 7.15 | 7.86 | 8.51 | 5.74 | 4.29 | 7.01 | 11.51 | 11.24 |
June | 4.31 | 3.31 | 3.30 | 4.11 | 7.36 | 8.10 | 8.49 | 5.28 | 4.32 | 7.42 | 11.49 | 11.24 |
July | 4.32 | 3.31 | 3.31 | 4.59 | 7.38 | 8.11 | 8.47 | 5.19 | 4.52 | 8.04 | 11.51 | 11.25 |
August | 4.30 | 3.30 | 3.33 | 4.60 | 7.38 | 8.10 | 8.26 | 4.76 | 4.65 | 8.50 | 11.51 | 11.08 |
September | 4.03 | 3.29 | 3.33 | 4.67 | 7.38 | 8.12 | 8.04 | 4.55 | 4.75 | 8.89 | 11.50 | |
October | 3.78 | 3.28 | 3.30 | 5.11 | 7.38 | 8.15 | 7.97 | 4.51 | 4.98 | 9.56 | 11.50 | |
November | 3.80 | 3.31 | 3.32 | 5.57 | 7.39 | 8.34 | 7.78 | 4.48 | 5.13 | 10.00 | 11.50 | |
December | 3.79 | 3.31 | 3.55 | 6.11 | 7.62 | 8.60 | 7.55 | 4.49 | 5.72 | 10.53 | 11.50 |
5. CETES RATE OF RETURN
Period | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 | 2021 | 2022 | 2023 | 2024 |
January | 4.15 | 3.14 | 2.67 | 3.08 | 5.83 | 7.25 | 7.95 | 7.04 | 4.22 | 5.50 | 10.80 | 11.28 |
February | 4.19 | 3.16 | 2.81 | 3.36 | 6.06 | 7.40 | 7.93 | 6.91 | 4.02 | 5.94 | 11.04 | 11.00 |
March | 3.98 | 3.17 | 3.04 | 3.80 | 6.32 | 7.47 | 8.02 | 6.59 | 4.08 | 6.52 | 11.34 | 10.90 |
April | 3.82 | 3.23 | 2.97 | 3.74 | 6.50 | 7.46 | 7.78 | 5.84 | 4.06 | 6.68 | 11.27 | 11.04 |
May | 3.72 | 3.28 | 2.98 | 3.81 | 6.56 | 7.51 | 8.07 | 5.38 | 4.07 | 6.90 | 11.25 | 11.03 |
June | 3.78 | 3.02 | 2.96 | 3.81 | 6.82 | 7.64 | 8.18 | 4.85 | 4.03 | 7.56 | 11.02 | 10.88 |
July | 3.85 | 2.83 | 2.99 | 4.21 | 6.99 | 7.73 | 8.15 | 4.63 | 4.35 | 8.05 | 11.09 | 10.87 |
August | 3.84 | 2.77 | 3.04 | 4.24 | 6.94 | 7.73 | 7.87 | 4.50 | 4.49 | 8.35 | 11.07 | 10.65 |
September | 3.64 | 2.83 | 3.10 | 4.28 | 6.99 | 7.69 | 7.61 | 4.25 | 4.69 | 9.25 | 11.05 | |
October | 3.39 | 2.90 | 3.02 | 4.69 | 7.03 | 7.69 | 7.62 | 4.22 | 4.93 | 9.00 | 11.26 | |
November | 3.39 | 2.85 | 3.02 | 5.15 | 7.02 | 7.83 | 7.46 | 4.28 | 5.05 | 9.70 | 11.78 | |
December | 3.29 | 2.81 | 3.14 | 5.61 | 7.17 | 8.02 | 7.25 | 4.24 | 5.49 | 10.10 | 11.26 |
6. INVESTMENT UNITS (UDIS)
The UDI is a unit of account of constant real value to denominate credit titles. It does not apply to checks, commercial contracts, or other acts of commerce.
Period | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 | 2021 | 2022 | 2023 | 2024 |
January | 4.89 | 5.10 | 5.29 | 5.41 | 5.62 | 5.97 | 6.25 | 6.44 | 6.64 | 7.12 | 7.69 | 8.06 |
February | 4.92 | 5.13 | 5.29 | 5.43 | 5.69 | 6.00 | 6.25 | 6.46 | 6.70 | 7.18 | 7.74 | 8.11 |
March | 4.94 | 5.15 | 5.30 | 5.44 | 5.71 | 6.02 | 6.26 | 6.49 | 6.75 | 7.24 | 7.77 | 8.11 |
April | 4.97 | 5.15 | 5.32 | 5.45 | 5.75 | 6.03 | 6.28 | 6.43 | 6.79 | 7.31 | 7.78 | 8.13 |
May | 4.96 | 5.13 | 5.29 | 5.42 | 5.75 | 6.01 | 6.27 | 6.42 | 6.81 | 7.33 | 7.78 | 8.15 |
June | 4.95 | 5.13 | 5.28 | 5.42 | 5.75 | 6.01 | 6.26 | 6.44 | 6.83 | 7.36 | 7.77 | 8.13 |
July | 4.95 | 5.14 | 5.28 | 5.42 | 5.76 | 6.04 | 6.27 | 6.49 | 6.87 | 7.43 | 7.79 | 8.20 |
August | 4.95 | 5.16 | 5.29 | 5.44 | 5.79 | 6.07 | 6.29 | 6.52 | 6.90 | 7.47 | 7.83 | 8.25 |
Sep. | 4.97 | 5.18 | 5.31 | 5.45 | 5.82 | 6.11 | 6.29 | 6.55 | 6.92 | 7.53 | 7.87 | |
Oct. | 4.99 | 5.20 | 5.33 | 5.49 | 5.84 | 6.13 | 6.31 | 6.57 | 6.97 | 7.57 | 7.90 | |
Nov. | 5.02 | 5.23 | 5.36 | 5.53 | 5.89 | 6.17 | 6.35 | 6.60 | 7.04 | 7.62 | 7.94 | |
Dec. | 5.06 | 5.27 | 5.38 | 5.56 | 5.93 | 6.23 | 6.39 | 6.61 | 7.11 | 7.65 | 7.98 |
En conclusión, las decisiones de financiamiento son cruciales para el desarrollo empresarial y económico de un país. A pesar de los avances teóricos desde Modigliani y Miller, aún no existe un consenso sobre la estructura óptima de capital. Es fundamental seguir investigando los factores internos y externos que influyen en estas decisiones para diseñar estrategias de financiamiento más efectivas. La integración de teorías recientes y un enfoque adaptado al contexto específico de cada país pueden contribuir a mejorar la competitividad y el desempeño financiero de las empresas.
REFERENCES
Ang, J. S. (1991). Small Business Uniqueness and the Theory of Financial Management, Journal of Small Business Finance, 1, 1–13. https://doi.org/10.57229/2373-1761.1108
Antoniou, A., Guney, Y. & Paudyal, K. (2008). The Determinants of Capital Structure: Capital Market-Oriented versus Bank-Oriented Institutions. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 43(1), 59-92. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109000002751
Arias, M., Arias, L., Pelayo, M. & Cobián, S. (2009). Factores Institucionales que Influyen en la Decisión de Estructura de Capital de las Empresas en México. Expresión Económica, 22, 49-63. https://doi.org/10.32870/eera.vi22.724
BANXICO. (2024). Sistema de Información Económica. Mexico: Banco de México. Link: https://www.banxico.org.mx/
Berger, A. N. & Udell, G. (1998). The economics of small business finance: the roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. Journal of Banking and Finance, 22, 613-673. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0378-4266(98)00038-7
Booth, L., Aivazian, V., Demirguc-Kunt, A. & Maksimovic, V. (2001). Capital Structures in Developing Countries. Journal of Finance, 56(1), 87-130.
Bradley, M., Harrell, G., & Kim, E. (1984). On the Existence of an Optimal Capital Structure: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Finance, 39(3), 97–120.
Cassar, G. (2004). The Financing of Business Start-Up, Journal of Business Venturing, 19(2), 261–283. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0883-9026(03)00029-6
De Angelo, H. & Masulis, R. (1980). Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxation. Journal of Financial Economics. 8, 3-29.
Denis, D. J. & Mihov, V. (2003). The choice among bank debt, non-bank private debt, and public debt: evidence from new corporate borrowings. Journal of Financial Economics, 70(1), 3-28. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(03)00140-5
Donaldson, G. (1961). Corporate Debt Capacity: A Study of Corporate Debt Policy and the Determination of Corporate Debt Capacity. Division of Research, Harvard University.
Gaytán, J. & Bonales, J. (2009). La Estructura de Capital En Filiales de Empresas Multinacionales de la Electrónica en Jalisco, Bajo Condiciones de Incertidumbre. México: Universidad de Guadalajara. Link: https://hdl.handle.net/20.500.12104/73829
Hernández, C. G. & Ríos B. H. (2012). Determinantes de la estructura financiera en la industria manufacturera: la industria de alimentos. Análisis económico 27(65), 101-121.
INEGI. (2024). Banco de Información Económica. Mexico: Instituto Nacional de Geografía y Estadística. Link: http://www.inegi.org.mx/sistemas/bie/
Kraus A. & Litzenberger, R. H. (1973). A state preference model of optimal financial leverage. Journal of Finance, 28(4), 911-922. https://doi.org/10.2307/2978343
Jensen, M. C. & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of financial economics, 3(4), 305-360. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X
Lemmon, M. L. . Zender, J. F. (2010). Debt capacity and tests of capital structure theories. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45(5), 1-49. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109010000499
Modigliani, F. & Miller, M. (1958). The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and The Theory of Investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261-297. http://www.jstor.org/stable/1809766
Modigliani, F. & Miller M. (1963). Corporate Income, Tax and the Cost of Capital: A Correction. The American Economic Review. 53(3). 433-443. http://www.jstor.org/stable/1809167
Myers, S. C. (1984). The capital structure puzzle. The Journal of Finance, 39(3), 574–592.
Myers, S. & Majluf, N. S. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions are made when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 187–221. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(84)90023-0
Romero, F. (2013). Variables financieras determinantes del fracaso empresarial para la pequeña y mediana empresa en Colombia: análisis bajo modelo Logit. Pensamiento & Gestión, 34, 235-277. http://www.scielo.org.co/scielo.php?pid=S1657-62762013000100012&script=sci_abstract&tlng=es
Ross, S. A., Westerfield, R. W. & Jordan, B. D. (2014). Fundamentos de Finanzas Corporativas, McGraw Hill.
Shyam-Sunder, L. & Myers, S. (1994). Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, pp. 51, 219–244. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(98)00051-8
Tudose, M. B. (2012). Capital Structure and Firm Performance. Economy Transdisciplinarity Cognition, 15(2), 76-82. https://www.ugb.ro/etc/etc2012no2/13_Tudose_final.pdf
Vargas, S. A. (2011). Estimación del Costo del Patrimonio y Costo del Capital por medio de tasas de rendimiento ajustadas al riesgo. Revista de Investigación & Desarrollo, 11(1), 118 – 135. http://dx.doi.org/10.23881/idupbo.011.1-2e